Generational theory, international history and current events
Skip to content
by aedens » Thu Aug 28, 2025 6:18 pm
by Higgenbotham » Thu Aug 28, 2025 12:00 pm
The modern world in so far as our interconnectedness, our complexity is in 29:38 many ways a buffer against small shocks. When a state begins to fail today, we 29:43 can very easily send resources, aid, peacekeepers, etc. to prop it back up. 29:49 And when you look at the best studies on state failure, they suggest that most states don't fail for anything longer 29:55 than roughly 6 months. Within that period, you usually have some kind of new rough and ready government which can 30:01 at least kind of try to impose rules, develop legislation, take taxes and extract resources and have something 30:08 like a monopoly on violence. And that's a good thing obviously in 30:13 many regards. But the problem of having this big interconnected complex system is that once the shock is big enough or 30:19 it hits the right location, suddenly it it's amplified throughout the entire system. And a good example of this of 30:26 course is the global financial crisis in 2008 where a housing bubble in the US 30:32 suddenly becomes a financial crisis on a global scale. Similarly, Covid 19 what 30:38 previous would have been potentially more of a local or regional pandemic that would have spread at the speed of a 30:43 horse became a global pandemic in the space of months if not weeks. We see the 30:50 same thing with things like ransomware attacks. They can travel at the speed of an internet connection. In short, our 30:57 interconnected complex globalized systems are fantastic in some ways, but when they become too interdependent, 31:02 they become transmitters and amplifiers of different shocks and risks. And that means that collapse 31:10 going to the future is probably more likely to be global rather than local or regional. And it's probably likely be 31:16 much worse than it was in the past.
by tim » Tue Aug 26, 2025 11:16 am
Money is no more than a medium of exchange. Only when it has a value acknowledged by more than one person can it be so used. The more general the acknowledgement, the more useful it is. Once no one acknowledged it, the Germans learnt, their paper money had no value or use - save for papering walls or making darts. The discovery which shattered their society was that the traditional repository of purchasing power had disappeared, and that there was no means left of measuring the worth of anything. For many, life became an obsessional search for Sachverte, things of ‘real’, constant value: Stinnes bought his factories, mines, newspapers. The meanest railway worker bought gewgaws. For most, degree of necessity became the sole criterion of value, the basis of everything from barter to behaviour. Man’s values became animal values. Contrary to any philosophic assumption, it was not a salutary experience. What is precious is that which sustains life. When life is secure, society acknowledges the value of luxuries, those objects, materials, services or enjoyments, civilised or merely extravagant, without which life can proceed perfectly well but which make it much pleasanter notwithstanding. When life is insecure, or conditions are harsh, values change. Without warmth, without a roof, without adequate clothes, it may be difficult to sustain life for more than a few weeks. Without food, life can be shorter still. At the top of the scale, the most valuable commodities are perhaps water and, most precious of all, air, in whose absence life will last only a matter of minutes. For the destitute in Germany and Austria whose money had no exchange value left existence came very near these metaphysical conceptions. It had been so in the war. In All Quiet on the Western Front, Müller died ‘and bequeathed me his boots - the same that he once inherited from Kemmerick. I wear them, for they fit me quite well. After me Tjaden will get them: I have promised them to him.’ In war, boots; in flight, a place in a boat or a seat on a lorry may be the most vital thing in the world, more desirable than untold millions. In hyperinflation, a kilo of potatoes was worth, to some, more than the family silver; a side of pork more than the grand piano. A prostitute in the family was better than an infant corpse; theft was preferable to starvation; warmth was finer than honour, clothing more essential than democracy, food more needed than freedom.
Much as it may have been recognised that stability would have to be arranged some day, and that the greater the delay the harder it would be, there never seemed to be a good time to invite trouble of that order. Day by day through 1920, 1921 and 1922 the reckoning was postponed, the more (not the less) readily as the prospective consequences of inflation became more frightening. The conflicting objectives of avoiding unemployment and avoiding insolvency ceased at last to conflict when Germany had both. The longer the delay, the more savage the cure. Austria by the end of 1922 was in the hands of the receivers, having regained a stable currency only under the absolute direction of a foreigner. Hungary, too, had passed any chance of self-redemption, and later on was to undergo an equal degree of hardship and suffering, especially for her public servants. Stability returned to Germany under a military dictatorship when much of the constitution had been suspended - although the State of Emergency was only indirectly necessitated by the destruction of the nation’s finances. To all three countries stability and then recovery came. All had to be bailed out by others. Each was obliged to accept a greater degree of economic disruption and unemployment than need ever have been feared at the time when the excessive printing of banknotes might still have been stopped. In all three cases, after inflation reached a certain advanced stage, financial and economic disaster seems to have been a prerequisite of recovery.
What really broke Germany was the constant taking of the soft political option in respect of money. The take-off point therefore was not a financial but a moral one; and the political excuse was despicable, for no imaginable political circumstances could have been more unsuited to the imposition of a new financial order than those pertaining in November 1923, when inflation was no longer an option. The Rentenmark was itself hardly more than an expedient then, and could scarcely have been introduced successfully had not the mark lost its entire meaning. Stability came only when the abyss had been plumbed, when the credible mark could fall no more, when everything that four years of financial cowardice, wrong-headedness and mismanagement had been fashioned to avoid had in fact taken place, when the inconceivable had ineluctably arrived.
by tim » Tue Aug 26, 2025 11:15 am
When war came back, so did inflation. With inflation alone, noted Günter Schmölders,55 can a government extinguish debt without repayment, or wage war and engage in other non-productive activities on a large scale: it is still not recognised as a tax by the tax-payer. Thus did Hitler resume deficit spending to finance armaments in 1938, and the experience begin again. As in the first case, the second inflation was a ten-year affair, although huge price inflation did not start in earnest until the eighth and ninth years, when cigarettes took over as the medium of exchange. In terms of public perception, however, the second inflation travelled much faster. By 1948 the Reichsmark was abandoned, and ten Reichsmarks were traded in in cash against the new Deutschmark, while bank accounts were credited with only 6.50 Deutschmarks for every 100 Reichsmarks. Disaster had struck the holders of money values once again, but the agony was contained very much more quickly. The pass to which the Reichsmark had come in 1947-1948, the loss of nine-tenths of its value, had been achieved by its predecessor, the mark, as early as 1919. Her new war indemnities apart, Germany was once again an almost debtfree country; and once again, with stability regained, great foreign loans were available to haul her out of her economic difficulties. Once again the repudiation of debt, conscious or unconscious, had been shown to be no more than a stage on the hyper-inflationary road. In the Toronto Star Weekly in December 1923, Ernest Hemingway described a street auction of inflation banknotes - German marks, Austrian kronen, Russian roubles - which the citizens of Toronto were being urged to buy in the hope, of which Germans, Austrians and Russians had long since been brutally robbed, that when sanity returned the banknotes, too, would retrieve their old values: No one explained to the listening men that the cheap-looking Russian money had been printed in million-rouble denominations as fast as the presses could work in order to wipe out the value of the old imperial money and in consequence the money-holding class. Now the Soviet has issued roubles backed by gold.
How great does inflation have to be before a government can no longer control it? Most economists accept that mild inflation has certain therapeutic advantages for a nation which must deal with the social and economic problems to which industrial democracies are usually subject. Most electorates still accept the statements of their politicians’ pious intentions in regard to controlling ever rising prices: and yet the Deutschmark, the currency of the country which had most reason to fear inflation, lost twothirds of its purchasing power between 1948 and 1975. The pound lost almost half its purchasing power between 1970 and 1975. In neither instance, however, did such depreciation represent a deliberate, cynical policy; which, no doubt, would also have been claimed by the German bankers and governments of the early 1920s, who looked for causes of their monetary difficulties beyond their own printing press and tax system - and found them, without difficulty and to their complete intellectual satisfaction. It remains so that once an inflation is well under way (as Schmölders has it) ‘it develops a powerful lobby that has no interest in rational arguments’. This was as true for Austria and Hungary as for Germany.
by tim » Tue Aug 26, 2025 11:07 am
Our Mafioso Economy Extortion is the keystone of America's Mafioso Economy.
And scene: here are the dons, each the ruthless head of their own vast organization, seated next to their wives in a show of bourgeois respectability, assembled by invitation to kiss the ring of the Godfather. This isn't just fiction, of course; we've all seen the photo of America's Big Tech dons, wives in tow, lined up in a display of billionaire obeisance. We all know the drill: give the Godfather respect and his cut, and you can return to your extractive monopoly confident that nobody is going to interrupt your grift. Welcome to America's Mafioso Economy, where monopolies are free to extract vast fortunes via addiction (pharmaceuticals, social media, gaming, pornography, gambling, entertainment, etc.), predatory pricing (oops, I mean dynamic pricing), shoddy goods and services, shakedowns, and of course, extortion: offers you can't refuse. For example, that software you could buy and use for years until the Mafioso Monopoly obsoleted it? Now you have to rent it. It's called a subscription service, which is like calling the addict's next hit of smack a subscription service. You have a need, and the Mafioso Monopoly will service your need, but monthly. So what once cost $200 now extracts $1,000 from your earnings. Same product (or worse), but now it costs a lot more. That's America's Mafioso Economy in a nutshell: same product or service, but now it costs more. And since the Mafioso Monopolies bought up all their competitors (an offer you can't refuse), there's no where else to turn, except perhaps another Mafioso member of a cartel. It's not just pay to play--you have to pay just to enter the auction of political favors. The Clinton Foundation set a new standard of Mafioso malignancy: "donate" to the foundation if you want access, then "donate" more if you want some actual action. Extortion is the keystone of America's Mafioso Economy. Apply a little pressure, make an offer they can't refuse, and voila. Nice little business / institution you got there, too bad it's about to be gutted by some new regulations or executive actions. There is a way to make it all go away, but it's going to cost you. Extortion pricing is Corporate America's playbook. Since every corporation Mafia deploys the same algos and extractive exploitation strategies, our choice boils down to which paddock we enter to get sheared. Our Stasi-style surveillance and AI-powered algos have detected you can pay more than your fellow debt-serfs, so the price of your airline seat, or grocery item, is higher than the other customers. It's not extortion because you could go to another member of the Mafia cartel, but alas, they use the same dynamic pricing, so too bad you passed up that initial price, now it's even higher. Junk fees abound because we have no choice. Where else can you buy a ticket to that concert you absolutely must attend? How about switching electrical utilities to get a better deal? Monopolies abound because they're the foundation of America's Mafioso Economy. Darth Vader understood the Empire is also a Mafioso structure. Once you gain power over supply and governance, then you're free to alter the deal at will. I have altered the deal, pray I don't alter it further.
by aedens » Tue Aug 26, 2025 9:17 am
by Higgenbotham » Mon Aug 25, 2025 5:59 pm
Robert Fosbury, an astrophysicist with an interest in the effect of light on biology, contends that “We made a huge unconscious mistake when we decided to change the lighting in the built environment.” In his collaborations with scientists in diverse disciplines, Fosbury reports, “What we’ve realized increasingly is that the removal of non-visible light from indoor lighting has been a catastrophe of the first order.” Fosbury likens what he views as “infrared starvation” caused by indoor environments devoid of infrared wavelengths to scurvy, a disease caused by a vital missing nutrient. In this case, the nutrient is infrared light. “We believe this is one of the main contributors to the gradual peaking and decline in public health that we’ve noticed over in the last decade or so,” he explains. “The increase in type 2 diabetes and obesity, in all the diseases of aging, and many of these things can be attributed to mitochondrial dysfunction.” Jeffery notes that the effects of limiting one’s exposure to this narrow range of light build up over time. “All the damaging things that come from blue light come from longer term blue light exposure,” he says. “If I want to undermine your mitochondria with blue light, I have to expose them for quite a long time consistently.”
by aedens » Mon Aug 25, 2025 11:26 am
by tim » Sun Aug 24, 2025 5:09 pm
In November, a year after the Armistice, Frau Eisenmenger wrote that her position was alarmingly worse, the financial situation beyond her understanding. The krone, at 25 Swiss centimes the previous Christmas, was now quoted at one-twelfth of a centime. Her shares, however, were going up. Gambling on the stock exchange had become the fashion - the only way to avoid losing all one’s money and perhaps to add to it. Many new bankers were giving people advice, the flight from the krone governing all transactions. ‘Meanwhile,’ Frau Eisenmenger wrote, the large numbers of unemployed, their passions fermented by the Communists, are seething with discontent … a mob has attempted to set the Parliament building on fire. Mounted policemen were torn from their horses, which were slaughtered in the Ringstrasse and the warm bleeding flesh dragged away by the crowd … the rioters clamoured for bread and work … Side by side with unprecedented want among the bulk of the population, there is a striking display of luxury among those who are benefitting from the inflation. New nightclubs are being opened. These clubs have the further effect of greatly intensifying the class hatred of the proletariate against the bourgeoisie.
Top